From Free Market Fundamentalism to
State Capitalism
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part
I: US Government
Pours Oil on Fire
Part
II: Treasury’s “Troubled Assets Relief Program”
in Trouble
This article appeared in AToL
on October 30, 2008 as: Killer touch for market
capitalism
Treasury Secretary
Henry Paulson asserts that the full resources of the Treasury
Department are being used to ensure the success of its $700 billion
Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP). The “full resources of
the Treasury Department” commands the full faith and credit of
the United States anchored by Treasury’s taxing authority as
approved by Congress. Tax payments in the US are made to the US
Treasury via the Internal Revenue Service.
The
Congress can approve taxes for and spending by the Administration,
but Congress cannot create money like the Federal Reserve can.
Treasury’s money can only come from future taxes approved by
Congress. Article I - Section 7.1 of the Constitution stipulates that
“All Bills for raising revenue shall originate in the House of
Representatives.” The Federal Reserve has the authority
to create money as part of its monetary policy prerogative but
Treasury does not have any constitutional authority to expand the
money supply. Treasury must depend on tax revenue for funds beyond
which Treasury must sell sovereign debt to raise funds up to the
national debt ceiling approved by Congress. Section 8.2 stipulates
that only Congress have the power to borrow money on the credit of
the United States. Proceeds from sovereign debt are advances on
sovereign liability and not revenue, and must be paid back from
future tax revenue.
Thus far, Congress has approved
$700 billion of taxpayer funds to be used by TARP. President Bush
also signed a $634 billion spending bill on September 30 that
includes funding for $25 billion in low-cost government loans for the
distressed auto industry. More public funds may be approved as
needed. Since the Federal government is and has been operating on a
fiscal deficit, these funds can only come out of future tax revenue
and/or more fiscal deficits.
Also, Treasury is coming
under increasing pressure to expand its financial rescue plan beyond
banks to include direct assistance to the ailing auto and insurance
sectors.
In recent days, lawmakers and interest groups have
stepped up their efforts to persuade the Bush administration to
divert part of the $700 billion authorized by Congress to additional
categories of companies that were not originally expected to be
rescued.
TARP gives the Treasury broad authority to buy
any assets that are important for the stability of the US financial
system. But participation in the sweeping $250 billion
recapitalization plan has so far been confined to US banks. On
October 24, the Financial Services Roundtable, an influential
lobbying group in Washington, sent a letter to Neel Kashkari, interim
assistant Treasury secretary for financial stability, a former
Goldman Sachs banker brought to the Treasury by Paulson, himself also
a former Goldman Sachs banker, urging the administration to consider
taking stakes in “broker-dealers, insurance companies [such as
Ambac and MBIA], and automobile companies [such as GM and Chrysler]”
as well as “institutions controlled by a foreign bank or
company” that play a vital role in the US economy by providing
liquidity to the market. A Treasury department spokeswoman declined
to comment on whether the US would consider expanding the rescue in
such a way.
Members of the Michigan congressional
delegation also sent a letter to the Treasury and the Federal Reserve
asking them to take steps to “promote liquidity” in the
US auto industry. It is true that cars are not selling because
leasing credit has frozen and collateral debt obligations (CDO)
backed by auto loans. But everyone knows the automakers are facing
insolvency in the long run beyond credit problems.
Separately, AIG, the insurer that had been rescued by the
government, revealed it had already used $72 billion of an $85
billion government loan and $18 billion of an additional $37.8
billion credit facility from the Fed.
An expansion of
the recapitalization plan beyond US banks would mark a significant
new chapter in the government’s response to the financial
crisis.
TARP’s Seven Policy Teams
Ten days after the new $700 billion TSRP was signed into law on
October 3, Treasury announced that it has created seven policy teams
to develop several tools and other important elements that are
required under the new law.
1)
Mortgage-backed securities purchase program: This team is
identifying which troubled assets to purchase with taxpayer funds,
from whom to buy them and which purchase mechanism will best meet
Treasury policy objectives “to protect taxpayers by making the
best use of their money.” Treasury is designing the
detailed auction protocols and will work with vendors to implement
the program.
For more than a year, the market has been
unable to identify with clarity troubled assets, their owners and how
such assets can be purchased and at what price. The uncertainty is
real and it has created justified fear of yet unknown losses in the
market. It is not likely that the new team at Treasury, no doubt
highly capable, can solve this riddle quicker than the market can
without the existence of a central clearing mechanism.
2) Whole loan
purchase program: Regional banks are particularly clogged with
whole residential mortgage loans that have not been securitized and
sold to dispersed investors. This team is working with bank
regulators to identify which types of loans to purchase first, how to
value them, and which purchase mechanism will best meet policy
objectives “to protect taxpayers by making the best use of
their money.” This is not a simple task. It would involve value
judgments and political calculations inherent in the policy
objectives. It is not clear how this program will work more effective
than market forces without distorting market value.
3) Insurance
program: Treasury said it is establishing a program to insure
troubled assets. It has several innovative ideas on how to structure
this program, including how to insure mortgage-backed securities as
well as whole loans. At the same time, it recognizes that there are
likely other good ideas out there that it could benefit from.
Accordingly, on Friday, October 10, Treasury submitted to the Federal
Register a public Request for Comment to solicit the best ideas on
structuring options. The Treasury was requiring responses within
fourteen days so it could consider them quickly, and begin designing
the program.
With many insurance companies on the
verge of insolvency from rising claims on counter-party defaults, the
Treasury’s insurance program on troubled assets looks like an
attempt to insure losses that have already occurred, in violation of
the basic principle of insurance.
4)
Equity purchase program: Treasury is designing a standardized
program to purchase equity in a broad array of financial
institutions. As with the other programs, the equity purchase program
will be voluntary and designed with attractive terms to encourage
participation from healthy institutions. It will also encourage firms
to raise new private capital to complement public capital.
On a voluntary basis, it is a puzzle why healthy institutions
would need or want to sell equity to the Treasury. On Tuesday,
October 14, an hour before the market opens in New York at 9:30 am,
Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson, Federal Reserve Chairman Ben
Bernanke and Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) Chairman
Sheila Bair, supported by SEC Chairman Christopher Cox, Commodity
Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) Chairman Walter Luken, Office of
controller of Currency (OCC) Controller John Dugan and Office of
Thrift Supervision (OTS) Chairman John Reich, announced that the
government will invest up to $250 billion in preferred stocks, half
of it at large banks. The lists of banks participating include
Goldman Sachs Group Inc. ($10 billion), Morgan Stanley ($10 billion),
JP Morgan Chase ($25 billion), Bank of America Corp. –
including the soon to be acquired Merrill Lynch ($25 billion),
Citigroup Inc. ($25 billion), Well Fargo ($25 billion), Bank of New
York ($3 billion), Mellon ($3 billion) and State Street Corp. ($2
billion). These moves are designed to keep money flowing through the
frozen banking system to keep the economy going.
The
government will purchase preferred stocks, an equity investment
designed to avoid hurting existing shareholders and deterring new
ones. The preferred stocks do not have voting rights, and carry a 5%
annual dividend that rises to 9% after five years. The government’s
plan will be structured to encourage firms to bring in private
capital. Firms returning capital to government by 2009 may get better
terms for the government’s stake. Financial institutions will
have until mid November to decide whether they want to participate in
the government recapitalization scheme. The minimum capital injection
will be 2% of risk-weighted assets and the maximum will be 3% of
risk-weighted assets, with an overall cap at $25 billion. Critics are
asking why the government is only getting 5% when Warren Buffet was
getting 10% guaranteed dividend in his recent investment in Goldman
Sachs.
The senior preferred shares will qualify as
Tier 1 capital and will rank senior to common stock and pari passu,
which is at an equal level in the capital structure, with existing
preferred shares, other than preferred shares which by their terms
rank junior to any other existing preferred shares. The senior
preferred shares will pay a cumulative dividend rate of 5% per annum
for the first five years and will reset to a rate of 9% per annum
after year five. The senior preferred shares will be non-voting,
other than class voting rights on matters that could adversely affect
the shares. The senior preferred shares will be callable at par after
three years. Prior to the end of three years, the senior preferred
may be redeemed with the proceeds from a qualifying equity offering
of any Tier 1 perpetual preferred or common stock. Treasury may also
transfer the senior preferred shares to a third party at any time. In
conjunction with the purchase of senior preferred shares, Treasury
will receive warrants to purchase common stock with an aggregate
market price equal to 15% of the senior preferred investment. The
exercise price on the warrants will be the market price of the
participating institution's common stock at the time of issuance,
calculated on a 20-trading day trailing average.
Executive compensation, including golden parachutes will be
limited at banks that accept government investments. The Fed will
guarantee all senior debts issued by banks over the next three years.
The FDIC, invoking a “systemic risk”
clause in Federal banking law, will provide unlimited insurance to
all non-interest-bearing accounts primarily used by businesses. The
cost of this insurance will come from user fees paid by banks outside
of the $700 billion TARP. It appears that the US has joined the
global race to guarantee bank deposits to prevent US bank deposit
from fleeing to countries with safer guarantee levels. This is billed
as a global coordination of all central banks while in reality is a
sign of rising financial nationalism.
5) Homeownership
preservation: The Treasury said when it purchases mortgages and
mortgage-backed securities, it will look for every opportunity
possible to help homeowners. This goal is consistent with other
programs - such as HOPE NOW - aimed at working with borrowers,
counselors and servicers to keep people in their homes. In this case,
Treasury is working with the Department of Housing and Urban
Development to maximize these opportunities to help as many
homeowners as possible, while also protecting taxpayers.
Yet none of the government programs launched so far have been
effective in helping homeowners because ready opportunities to help
them have not been found. The bottom line is that it is not possible
to help distressed homeowners and protect taxpayer money at the same
time.
6)
Executive compensation: The law sets out important
requirements regarding executive compensation for firms that
participate in the TARP. This team is working hard to define the
requirements for financial institutions to participate in three
possible scenarios: One, an auction purchase of troubled assets; two,
a broad equity or direct purchase program; and three, a case of an
intervention to prevent the impending failure of a systemically
significant institution.
Management would opt for
bankruptcy protection if executive compensation should be more
liberal under bankruptcy than participation in the TARP. Also,
the interconnected nature of financial markets nowadays has produced
a large number of “systemically significant institutions.”
7)
Compliance: The law establishes important oversight and
compliance structures, including establishing an Oversight Board,
on-site participation of the General Accounting Office and the
creation of a Special Inspector General, with thorough reporting
requirements. The Treasury said it welcomes this oversight and has a
team focused on making sure it gets it right.
The Impact of Leverage and De-leverage on Asset Price
The accumulation of assets via massive amounts of debt
is known in finance as leverage, expressed as debt-equity ratio.
Leveraging can push up the price of assets so acquired and
de-leveraging can push down the price of such assets.
A
broker-dealer trades securities for customers as well as for
proprietary accounts. In US markets, a broker-dealer must register
with the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority, a self-regulating
organization under the Security Exchange Act of 1934 as part of the
New Deal. When executing trade orders on behalf of a customer, the
institution is said to be acting as a broker. When executing trades
for its own account, the institution is said to be acting as a
dealer.
Many broker-dealers had been routinely
leveraged to over 30 times during the credit bubble released the Fed
under Alan Greenspan. Firms are now frantically trying to bring
leverage down to below 20 times, still twice as high as what was
considered prudent by the SEC since 1975 until the net capital rule
was exempted for five major institutions in 2004.
The
net capital rule created by the SEC in 1975 required broker-dealers
to limit their debt-to-net-capital ratio to 12-to-1, and they must
issue early warnings if they began approaching this limit, and were
forced to stop trading if they exceeded it, so broker-dealers often
kept their debt-to-net capital ratios much lower than 12-1. The rule
allowed the SEC to oversee broker-dealers, and required firms to
value all of their tradable assets at market prices. The rule applied
a haircut, or a discount, to account for the assets’ market
risk. Equities, for example, had a haircut of 15%, while a 30-year
Treasury bill, because it is less risky, had a 6% haircut. But a 2004
SEC exemption -- given only to five big firms -- allowed them to
lever up 30 and even 40 to 1.
The five big firms
wanted for their brokerage units an exemption from the 1975
regulation that limited the amount of debt they could take on to $12
for every dollar of equity. The exemption would unshackle billions of
dollars held in reserve as a cushion against losses on their
investments. Those equity funds could then flow up to the parent
company, enabling it to invest in the fast growing but opaque world
of mortgage-backed securities, credit derivatives, credit default
swaps - a form of insurance for bond holders - and other
exotic structured finance instruments.
In 2004,
the European Union passed a rule allowing the SEC’s European
counterpart to manage the risk both of broker dealers and their
investment banking holding companies. In response, the SEC instituted
a similar, voluntary program for broker-dealers with capital of at
least $5 billion, enabling the agency to oversee both the
broker-dealers and the holding companies. Ever since the Great
Depression, the government has tried to limit the leverage available
to the public in the US stock market by maintain margin requirements.
But regulators, led by former chairman of the Federal Reserve Alan
Greenspan, thought financial innovation would be hampered, and
financial activity driven to unregulated market overseas, if there
were any attempts to impose limits on leverage in the unregulated
credit and capital markets. After all, innovation was viewed as the
driving force in US prosperity. The global financial system embarked
on a race to assume more risk under a mentality of “if I don’t
smoke, somebody else will.”
This brave new
approach, which all five qualifying broker-dealers - Bear Stearns,
Lehman Brothers, Merrill Lynch, Goldman Sachs, and Morgan Stanley -
voluntarily adopted, altered the way the SEC measured their capital.
The five big firms led the charge for the net capital rule change to
promote financial innovation, spearheaded by Goldman Sachs, then
headed by Henry Paulson, who two years later, would leave Goldman to
become the Treasury Secretary, who now has to deal with the
global mess created by high leverage.
Using
computerized models provided by the five big firms, the SEC, under
its new Consolidated Supervised Entities (CSE) program, allowed the
broker-dealers to increase their debt-to-net-capital ratios,
sometimes, as in the case of Merrill Lynch, to as high as 40-to-1. It
also removed the method for applying haircuts, relying instead on
another math-based computerized model for calculating risk that led
to a much smaller discount.
The SEC justified the less
stringent capital requirements by arguing it was now able to manage
the consolidated entity of the broker-dealer and the holding company,
which would ensure better management of risk. “The Commission’s
2004 rules strengthened oversight of the securities markets, because
prior to their adoption there was no formal regulatory oversight, no
liquidity requirements, and no capital requirements for investment
bank holding companies,” a spokesman for the agency
rationalized.
In loosening the capital rule, which was
supposed to provide a buffer in turbulent times, the SEC also decided
to rely on the five big firms’ own computer risk models,
essentially outsourcing the job of monitoring risk to the banks it
was supposed to supervise. Over subsequent years, all would take
advantage of the looser capital rule to increase leverage.
The leverage ratio - a measurement of how much the companies were
borrowing compared to their total assets - rose sharply at Bear
Stearns, to 33 to 1. In other words, for every dollar in equity, it
had $33 of debt. The ratio at the other firms also
rose significantly. This advantage enabled the Big Five to go on
a frenzy of acquisition, expanding risk to the entire financial
system. The abuse of leverage was particularly severe in the hedge
fund industry in which the Big Five were big players both in
proprietary funds and as broker-dealer for large hedge funds who in
turn were highly leveraged.
The SEC did
reexamine its efficacy after the Bear Stearns collapse. “Immediately
after the events of mid-March, when the run-on-the-bank phenomenon to
which Bear Stearns was exposed demonstrated the importance of
incorporating loss of short-term secured funding into regulatory
stress scenarios, the Consolidated Supervised Entities (CSE) program
revised the analysis of liquidity risk management, with enhanced
focus on the use and resilience of secured funding,” Securities
and Exchange Commission Chairman Christopher Cox testified at the
July 2008 hearing. “The SEC has also worked closely with the
Federal Reserve in directing this additional stress testing.”
Two months after Chairman Cox testified, however, two
more broker-dealers collapsed, and one of the two remaining
broker-dealers - Morgan Stanley - was in talks to merge with Wachovia
which itself was in trouble and had to be taken over by Wells Fargo.
It is now clear that the SEC leverage modification in 2004 is a
primary reason for the massive losses that have occurred in 2008.
On Sept. 26, 2008, Chairman Cox announced a decision by the SEC
Division of Trading and Markets to end the Consolidated Supervised
Entities (CSE) program, created in 2004 as a way for global
investment bank conglomerates that lack a supervisor under law to
voluntarily submit to regulation. Chairman Cox also described the
agency’s plans for enhancing SEC oversight of the broker-dealer
subsidiaries of bank holding companies regulated by the Federal
Reserve, based on the recent Memorandum of Understanding (MOU)
between the SEC and the Fed.
Chairman Cox made the
following statement along with the SEC announcement on ending the
CSE:
The last six months have made it abundantly clear that voluntary regulation does not work. When Congress passed the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act [on November 12, 1999 to repeal the Glass-Steagall Act of 1933 which had prohibited a bank from offering investment banking and insurance services], it created a significant regulatory gap by failing to give to the SEC or any agency the authority to regulate large investment bank holding companies, like Goldman Sachs, Morgan Stanley, Merrill Lynch, Lehman Brothers, and Bear Stearns.
The SEC said it has no plans to re-examine the impact
of the 2004 changes to the net capital rule, yet it put out a
proposal to revise the rule once again. This time, it is looking to
remove the requirement that broker-dealers maintain a certain rating
from the ratings agencies.
On Sept. 26, the commission
formally ended the 2004 program, acknowledging that it had failed to
anticipate the problems at Bear Stearns and the four other major
investment banks.
When the need to de-leverage is
triggered by insufficient revenue, asset prices will fall and
insolvency can result. Undercapitalization is merely a euphemism for
insolvency unless new capital can be raised quickly. Recapitalization
is a euphemism for dilution of sunk equity with new capital.
Recapitalization alters the capital structure of a corporation. It is
often accomplished by an exchange of bonds for stocks. Pending
bankruptcy is a common reason for recapitalization. Debentures might
be exchanged for reorganization bonds that pay interest only when
earned.
Under US law, a healthy company might seek to
save taxes by replacing preferred stock with bonds to gain interest
deductibility from its tax liabilities. In corporate finance,
in-substance defeasance is a technique whereby a corporation
discharges old, low rate debt prior to maturity without repaying it.
The corporation uses newly purchased securities with a lower face
value but paying a higher interest or having a higher market value.
The objective is to produce a more debt free balance sheet and
increase earnings in the amount by which the face amount of the old
debt exceeds the cost of the new securities.
The use
of defeasance in modern corporate finance began in 1982 when Exxon
bought and put into an irrevocable trust $312 million of US
government securities yielding 14% to provide for the repayment of
principal and interest on $515 million of old debt paying 5.8% to
6.7% and maturing in 2009. Exxon removed the defeased debt from
its balance sheet and added $132 million – the after tax
difference between $515 million and $312 million – to its
earnings in that quarter. In-substance defeasance may well the magic
bullet to get out from the curse of over leverage.
Global
stock markets staged a historic rally on Monday September 13 as
European governments pledged a total of €1.87 trillion ($2.55
trillion) to shore up their banking system and the US prepared to
unveil its own comprehensive rescue plan a day later. In New York,
the S&P 500, which the week before fell 18.2%, rose 11.6% –
the biggest daily gain since the volatile trading of the Great
Depression. The Dax index of the Frankfurt stock exchange closed up
11.4% while the CAC40 in Paris rose 11.2%. In London, the FTSE 100
rose 8.3%, its second largest one-day gain in history, and in Hong
Kong, the Hang Seng index rose 10.24%. Yet, the Treasury announcement
on Tuesday September 14 failed to extend the one-day market rally
that had greeted every one of the government’s
precedent–breaking previous measures. All the
governmental spectaculars failed to break the secular bear market in
which each rebound fails to breach the previous low.
Three-month Sterling Libor was just 2 basis points lower at about
6.25%, more than 2 percentage points above where markets are pricing
UK interest rates and higher than where the rate set before the
coordinated interest rate cuts by major economies in the second week
of October. Similarly, euro three-month Libor, which was down 7.37
basis points at 5.225% on October 14, remained high. There were only
weak signs of relief in the frozen credit markets at the centre of
the financial crisis, as three-month dollar Libor eased to 4.75% from
4.82%, even after the Fed lowered the Fed funds rate target to 1.5%
on October 8 and 3-month treasuries were yielding 0.5%. This left the
so-called Ted spread, which measures the difference between
inter-bank lending rates and risk-free government lending rates, at a
hefty 420 basis points.
Recapitalization, while
lowering leverage to protect the market value of debt, further
depresses asset value. Such are the laws of finance in market
economies. For this reason, taxpayers may never recoup their
investment in the Treasury’s nationalization program of the
banking system if government funds received by banks are used to
de-leverage rather than new lending.
The US
government’s misguided approach of monetizing illiquid assets
held by distressed institution to remove insolvency threats is self
defeating. In each step, it has predictably failed to jump start
credit and capital markets under seizure because excessive liquidity
cannot be cured by more liquidity. Assets become illiquid because
their price stubbornly stays above their market value. Such assets
will stay illiquid until price adjustments bring about market
transactions. Government monetization of illiquid assets will only
prolong their illiquid life span.
Markets are not the
best intermediaries of long-term value, because for market economies,
markets are the prime intermediaries of short-term value. This is why
economist Hyman Minsky thought that a substantial public sector is
needed to moderate short-term volatility in the private market
sector. When the private market sector dominates the economy, the
price regime will be excessively tilted by short-term conditions.
Markets can only function when there are matching numbers of
willing buyers and sellers at any one time. When the number of
sellers is larger than the number of buyers, prices will fall, or in
a reverse situation, prices will rise until the number of buyers and
sellers match up. Price is the point where willing sellers and
willing buyers meet for a fair transaction. Until the price is right,
the market remains in suspension. Price fluctuation then is the key
factor in addressing imbalances between buyers and sellers in the
market. This is both the strength and the weakness of market
economies.
Free markets require an equal degree of
market power between buyers and sellers. Ideally, a truly free market
always leaves both buyers and sellers happy, each being satisfied
that the transaction price reflects their differing judgment of fair
market value at t he point of transaction. The buyer thinks he will
gain from future appreciation and the seller thinks he will avoid
loss from future depreciation. Only one party in the transaction will
turn out to be right at any future point in time. The probability of
being wrong is the risk in the transaction. That is the basic
principle of market fundamentalism, which is governed by the
principle of fluctuating supply and demand through time,
intermediated by fluctuation in price.
When market
power is not equally distributed among market participants, a free
market is replaced by a coerced market. A coerced market is one when
one side, either buyers or seller, has more market power. Uneven
market power distorted prices to generate market inefficiency. A
failed market is one when there are no buyers or sellers at any
price. The ultimate coerced market is one where the government, which
by definition possesses overwhelming market power by virtue of it s
ability to print money by fiat, is the only buyer or seller. Market
fundamentalists are right in their belief that government should stay
away from the market to avoid destroying the market. Yet they are
wrong in thinking that government should deregulate markets to keep
it free. And above all, they are dangerously wrong in thinking that
markets can satisfy all economic needs. The truth is that there are
large segments of the economy that only government can handle
effectively and efficiently, national defense being one obvious
example. This government economic segment is known as the public
sector in a market economy. As economist Hyman Minsky pointed out
insightfully, the public sector performs a much needed function in
stabilizing the business cycle in the private sector. A society
without an adequate public sector leans towards economic anarchy that
will eventually implode.
In finance, to make a market
means maintaining ready, firm bids and offer prices in a given
security by standing ready to buy or sell at publicly quoted prices
in round lots (generally accepted units of trading on a securities
exchange – on the New York Stock exchange, a round lot is 100
shares for stock and $1000 or $5000 par value for bonds). The dealer
is called a market maker in the over-the-counter market outside of
exchanges. On the exchanges, the dealer is called a specialist. A
dealer who makes a market over a long period is said to “maintain”
a market.
The NASDAG requires that there be at least
two market makers for each stock listed in the system. The bid and
asked quotes are compared to ensure that the quote is a
representative spread. Registered competitive traders in the NYSE are
market makers because, in addition to trading for their own accounts,
they are expected to help correct an imbalance of orders. Registered
competitive traders are NYSE members who buy and sell for their own
accounts. Because their members pay no commission, they are able to
profit from even small changes in market prices, thus tend to trade
actively with high volume. Like specialists, registered competitive
traders must abide by exchange rules, including a requirement that
75% of their trade be stabilizing, meaning they cannot sell unless
the last trading price on a stock is up, or buy unless the last
trading price was down. Orders from the trading public take
precedence over those of registered competitive traders, which
normally account for less than 1% of total volume.
The central bank cannot be a market maker because the central
bank is empowered to create new money. This power to create new money
gives the central bank unequalled market power and turns it from a
market maker into a market destroyer. Throughout history, the
sovereign who enjoys the power of seigniorage refrain from being a
market participant for good reasons. When the sovereign owns
everything, there is no way to tell how much the sovereign is worth.
This is why even in a communist society where the people as sovereign
own the means of production, markets are still required to establish
prices to efficiently allocate economic and financial resources.
The government’s intervention has created a relative
advantage for companies to raising funds through guaranteed bank
paper versus the asset-backed markets. The ability of banks and other
financial groups to raise money via government guarantees means
funding through more traditional routes like asset-backed securities
will be much more expensive. In the short-term, the government moves
is having an effect. There has not been any issuance in credit cards
because all the major banks now have another, cheaper option. In
addition to offering banks cheaper sources of funding, the explicit
government guarantees on many bank securities has led to a sell-off
in bonds issued by mortgage financiers like Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac, as well as asset-backed securities. As a result, the cost of
borrowing in asset-backed markets has soared, with the premiums over
US government bonds at record highs. This makes private sector
funding even less attractive.
There are also signs
that government funds are being used by banks to buy rivals, rather
than provide new lending. On Friday, October 14, PNC Financial became
the first bank to make use of the US government’s bank
recapitalization program to merge with a weaker rival. In the longer
term, credit card debt securitization have to be revived because the
government programs are not large enough to cover all the banks’
funding needs.
Central Banks Have Become Market
Destroyers
The recent opening of the Federal
Reserve discount window to borrowings by commercial banks,
collateralized by illiquid assets, and the extension of discount
window access to investment banks have pushed the central bank across
the line of being a lender of last resort to being a market
destroyer. It is no wonder that its liquidity injection moves have
failed to moderate seizure of global credit markets. This is because
the central bank, not constrained by the supply and market value of
money, can set the price of illiquid asset by fiat, thus destroy the
very function of the market in setting meaningful prices that can
defuse market seizure. Central bank intervention into credit
markets to artificially support asset prices above market levels
carries no fundamental market implication, save the impact of future
inflation. The market knows that asset prices assigned by the central
bank are not real and will be adjusted downward as soon as central
bank intervention ends. And until central bank intervention ends, the
market remains in suspension.
This explains why
despite central bank intervention, and perhaps even because of it,
inter-bank lending stayed halted, with LIBOR (London Inter-bank
Lending Rate) rising high above normal spread over Fed funds rate
targets. In the non-banking financial sector, new commercial paper
issuance, the short-term funding source of choice for financial and
non-financial corporations, could not find buyers. In sum, global
credit markets continue to fail despite escalating and increasingly
desperate government intervention measures.
One of the
key objections behind the House of Representative initial rejection
of the Treasury’s $700 billion rescue package was that at the
end of the rescue term of 30 years, the public may not be paid back
on account that the illiquid collateral might still not yield returns
that match after inflation face values. The overvaluation of such
illiquid assets cannot be made whole through inflation because
de-leveraging made possible by inflation will keep the market value
of such assets below its after inflation face value. The
congressional opposition wanted prearranged authority to tax the
finance industry to recoup the investment for the public whose tax
money was being used for the rescue of distressed institutions.
The market was more honest than most paid pundits and
special interest policymakers. Market participants knew the crisis
was not merely a passing liquidity crunch, but a widespread
insolvency created by excessive asset value unsupported by
compensatory revenue. Insolvency will translate into sharp declines
in asset price. The government can destroy the market in the name of
saving it but the laws of market cannot be negated by government
intervention.
Some critics have mistakenly complained
that the US government has turned to socialism for solution to the
current financial crisis in a capitalistic system. Yet what the US
government has done is merely turning failed market capitalism into
state capitalism. Nationalization alone does not lead to socialism.
Socialism is not merely collective ownership of the means of
production. It must also subscribe to an operative goal of fair
sharing of the fruits of the economy through collective ownership of
the means of production.
In a socialist state,
state-owned enterprises are the venue of socialist ownership of the
means of production which is deployed to support the interests of
workers. But in a capitalist state, state-owned enterprises do not
entertain such populist goals. State capitalism continues to oppress
workers for the benefit of capital while the state represents the
interest of capitalists rather than workers. State capitalism
subscribes to the trickling down theory – saving the banks to
save the citizenry. What is needed is for government to save the
citizenry by direct assistance with job creations and wage
guarantees, not inter-bank loan guarantees.
Incoming data for September showed unemployment at 6.1% and still
climbing, above the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment
(NAIRU) of 6%. Non-farm payroll employment declined by 159,000; in a
civilian labor force of 154.7 million, with a labor force
participation rate of 66%. Total employment was 145.3 million
and the employment-population ratio was 62%. Since a recent
high in December 2006, the employment-population ratio has declined
by 1.4 percentage points. The number of persons who worked part
time for economic reasons rose by 337,000 to 6.1 million in
September, an increase of 1.6 million over the past 12 months.
This category includes persons who would like to work full time but
were working part time because their hours had been cut back or
because they were unable to find full-time jobs. These data suggests
an extremely weak economy going forward.
The entire
global market economy, fueled by decades of excess liquidity and debt
denominated in fiat dollars imprudently released by the US Federal
Reserve, had turned even prudent debt to equity ratios in normal
times into precariously over-leveraged debt structures. Asset price
inflation, defined as growth by central banking doctrine, had allowed
the global market economy to assume debt levels that could not be
serviced by relatively stagnant or even falling wage income. In an
asset price bubble unsupported by corresponding rise in wage income,
even normally prudent debt-equity ratios will result in precarious
debt leverage.
Either wage income must rise, or asset
prices must fall to restore financial equilibrium. Government
intervention to prop up inflated asset prices without compensatory
wage rise will only end in hyperinflation.
A sharp
decline in assets prices will unavoidably spell widespread bankruptcy
for many financially overextended companies and individuals. This
will constrict demand temporarily to delay inflation effects but
hyperinflation will result as certainly as the sun will rise because
modern democracies cannot allow deflation to cause widespread
bankruptcy even in a debt bubble. In my January 11, 2006 AToL
article: Of
debt, deflation and rotten apples, I wrote (Central banks fear
deflation more than inflation): “Although Greenspan
never openly acknowledges it, his great fear is not inflation, but
deflation, which is toxic in a debt-driven economy. ‘Price
stability’ is a term that increasingly refers to
anti-deflationary objectives, to keep prices up rather than down.”
By now, it is becoming clear that government
policy has been mostly focused on maintaining asset price at levels
that the market has rejected. Logic suggests that such a
policy will result in hyperinflation at
the end of the day that will lead to more bankruptcies down the road
in a protracted downward spiral. The government’s attempt to
save overextended financial institutions may
well cause the total destruction of market capitalism. And if
past experience is any guide, unless wage income is indexed to
inflation, the dilution of asset value through inflation will only
hasten the arrival of total market failure and a total melt
down of the market economy.
So far, not much is
heard from official circles that suggest the solution to the current
credit crisis can only come from an immediate and substantial rise in
wage income. Instead of bailing out insolvent financial institutions,
the government should use sovereign credit to maintain full
employment and boost wage income to catch up with inflated asset
prices. If the Fed must print new money to save the system, the new
money should go to job creation and wage increases rather than to
recapitalize insolvent corporations. Full employment and
rising wages will halt the fall of asset prices with a rising floor.
The approach adopted by the Bush administration is not
designed to rescue a collapsing global economy from total meltdown
but to resurrect free market capitalism from ideological bankruptcy
with state capitalism.
October 26, 2008